Soon after the news of the SEC securities fraud lawsuit against Elon Musk, Tim Newman tweeted “Finally says @streetwiseprof.” Indeed I did.
I am mildly surprised, but presumably Musk’s actions were so outrageous that the SEC couldn’t avoid taking action.
Although it shouldn’t be an issue, because Musk had to have known that his going private tweets were false, the law forecloses any “it was secured in my own mind” defense: recklessness–that he should have known the tweets were materially false–satisfies the scienter requirement. At least that’s the case for the civil action: I’m not sure about any criminal action by the DOJ.
Several people emailed me soon after the announcement, and my response was (in addition to “It’s about time”): Is this just the first step? Will the SEC (and perhaps DOJ) expand its investigation, and eventually legal action, to include Musk’s myriad previous dodgy statements? SolarCity came to mind. This SeekingAlpha post has a nice summary of some(!) of the others:
There’s been plenty of talk regarding SEC action since the day Elon Musk issued the go private tweet. With the news out Thursday, many would argue that a substantial overhang has been lifted from the stock, but of course, it brings up a lot of other issues that I’ve detailed above. Unfortunately, investors should consider the possibility that more shoes will drop.
There already have been many lawsuits filed from investors who have lost money during this whole fiasco. Additionally, there may be even more action from a number of government bodies. Who knows if the SEC is looking at other items like the Model 3 production ramp or the mysterious solar roof product? Perhaps they might even take a look at this blog post where Elon Musk talked about discussions for going private going back two years. He’s bought tens of millions in Tesla shares since, so would that be trading on material non-public information (insider trading)? Perhaps an investigation is started related to end of quarter sales tactics, where it seems Tesla is holding back deliveries of vehicles despite consumers paying for them. Some say this would be an effort to add much needed cash to the balance sheet or book unearned revenues for quarter’s end.
Not to mention missed production deadlines, the supercharger rollout, and on and on and on. And what could a deep dive into Tesla’s accounting reveal?
Elon’s co-dependents, AKA the Tesla Board of Directors, came out in his support.
Good luck with that! Though truth be told, they are so deeply connected to Elon that it would be pointless to try to cut loose from him now: their best bet is to go to the mattresses with him. Not a good bet, but their best one.
A friend has repeatedly asked me why haven’t there been class action lawsuits. My reply: not until there is a big break in the stock price. That is occurring now. So I wouldn’t stand in front of federal courthouses in the SDNY or NDCal for fear of being trampled by class action attorneys rushing to file.
The knock-on effects of this are many. As I’ve written repeatedly, despite Elon’s denials (another possible legal vulnerability!) Tesla needs cash. I don’t see a public equity or debt raise being remotely possible now, which would cripple the company’s ability to grow–and fulfill Elon’s grandiose promises. Moreover, Elon has borrowed extensively against Tesla stock. Margin call, anyone? And if that happens, what will he do and how will that impact the stock?
It was only a matter of time before Elon’s words–and his tweets–came back to haunt him. The only surprise is that it took such a long time. But his aura as a visionary protected him.
There is an element of Greek tragedy here. Hubris brings nemesis. To say that Elon exhibited hubris is the understatement of the century. If nemesis is even remotely proportional to hubris, he is in for hellish torments.
This Bloomberg piece from last month claims that the International Maritime Organization’s looming 2020 caps on sulfur emissions from ships “could lift crude prices by $4 a barrel when the measures come into effect in 2020.”
The IMO regulation will have different impacts on different crudes. It will no doubt cause the spread between sweet and sour crudes to widen. This happened in 2008, when European regulation mandating low sulfur diesel kicked in: this regulation contributed to the spike in benchmark Brent and WTI prices, and wide spreads in crude prices. During this time, (if memory serves) 10 VLCCs full of Iranian crude were swinging at anchor while WTI and Brent prices were screaming higher and sweet crude inventories were plunging precisely due to the fact that the regulation increased the demand for sweet crude and depressed demand for heavier, more sour varieties.
The IMO regulation will definitely reduce the demand for crude oil overall. The demand for crude is derived from the demand for fuels, notably transportation fuels. The regulation increases the cost of some transportation fuels, which decreases the (derived) demand for crude. This change will not be distributed evenly, with demand for light, sweet crudes actually increasing, but demand for sour crudes falling, with the fall being bigger, the more sour the crude.
The regulation will hit ship operators hard, and they will pass on the higher cost to shippers. In the short run, carriers will eat some of the cost–perhaps the bulk of it. But the long run supply elasticity of shipping is large (arguably close to perfectly elastic), meaning after fleet size adjusts shippers will bear the brunt.
The burden will fall heaviest on commodities, for which shipping cost is large relative to value. Therefore, farmers and miners will receive lower prices, and consumers will pay higher prices for commodity-intensive goods. Further, this regulatory tax will be highly regressive, falling on relatively low income individuals, who pay a higher share of their income on such goods.
This seems to be a case of almost all pain, little gain. The ostensible purpose of the regulation is to reduce pollution from sulfur emissions. Yes, ships will produce less such emissions, but due to the joint product nature of refined petroleum, overall sulfur emissions will fall far less.
Many ships currently use “bottom of the barrel” fuel oil that tend to be higher in sulfur. Many will achieve compliance by shifting to middle distillates. But the bottom of the barrel won’t go away. Over the medium to longer term, refineries will make investments that allow them to squeeze more middle distillates out of a barrel of crude, or to remove some sulfur, but inevitably refineries will produce some low-quality, high sulfur products: the sulfur has to go somewhere. This is inherent in the joint nature of fuel production.
And yes, there will be some adjustments on the crude supply side, with the differential between sweet and sour crude favoring production of the former over the latter. But sour crudes will be produced, and new discoveries of sour crude will be developed.
Meaning that although consumption of high sulfur fuels by ships will go down, since (a) in equilibrium consumption equals production, and (b) due to the joint nature of production the output of high sulfur fuels will go down less than its consumption by ships does, someone will consume most of the fuel oil that ships no longer used. And since someone is consuming it, they will emit the sulfur.
The ultimate result will be a regulation that basically shifts who produces the sulfur emissions, with a far smaller impact on the total amount of emissions.
This represents a tragic–and classic–example of a regulation imposed on a segment of a larger market. The pernicious effects of such a narrow regulation are particularly acute in oil, due to the joint nature of production.
Given the efficiency and distributive effects of the IMO, it is almost certainly not a second best policy. Indeed, it is more likely to be a second worst policy. Or maybe a first worst policy: doing nothing at all is arguably better.
Some other power traders–this time in the US–blowed up real good. Actually preceding the Aas Nasdaq default by some months, but just getting attention in the mainstream press today, a Houston-based power trading company–GreenHat–defaulted on long-term financial transmission rights contracts in PJM. FTRs are financial contracts that have cash-flows derived from the spread between prices at different locations in PJM. Locational spreads in power markets arise due to transmission congestion, so FTRs can be used to hedge the risk of congestion–or to speculate on it. FTRs are auctioned regularly. In 2015 GreenHat bought at auction FTRs for 2018. These positions were profitable in 2015 and 2016, but improvements in PJM transmission caused them to go underwater substantially in 2018. In June, GreenHat defaulted, and now PJM is dealing with the mess.
PJM members are on the hook for the defaulted positions. The positions were underwater to the tune of $110 million as of June–and presumably this was based on market prices, meaning that the cost of liquidating these positions would be multiples of that. In other words, this blow up could put Aas to shame.
PJM operates the market on a credit system, and market participants can be required to post additional collateral. However, long-term FTR credit is determined only on an annual basis: “In conjunction with the annual update of historical activity that is used in FTR credit requirement calculations, PJM will recalculate the credit requirement for long-term FTRs annually, and will adjust the Participant’s credit requirement accordingly. This may result in collateral calls if requirements increase.” Credit on shorter-dated positions are calculated more frequently: what triggered the GreenHat default was a failure to make its payment on its June FTR obligation.
This event is resulting in calls for a re-examination of PJM’s FTR credit scheme. As well it should! However, as the Aas episode demonstrates, it is a fraught exercise to determine the exposure in electricity spread transactions. This is especially true for long-dated positions like the ones GreenHat bought.
The PJM episode reinforces the Aas episode’s lessons the challenges of handling defaults–especially of big positions in illiquid instruments. Any auction is very likely to turn into a fire sale that exacerbates the losses that caused the default in the first place. Moral of the story: mutualizing default risk (either through a CCP, or a membership organization like PJM) can impose big losses on the participants in risk pool.
The dilemma is that the instruments in question can provide valuable benefits, and that speculators can be necessary to achieve these benefits. FTRs are important because they allow hedging of congestion risk, which can be substantial for both generation and load: locational spreads can be very volatile due to a variety of factors, including the lack of storability of power, non-convexities in generation (which can make it very costly to reduce generation behind a constraint), and generation capacity constraints and inelastic demand (which make it very costly to increase generation or reduce consumption on the other side of the constraint). So FTRs play a valuable hedging role, and in most markets financial players are needed to absorb the risk. But that creates the potential for default, and the very factors that make FTRs valuable hedging tools can make defaults very costly.
FTR liquidity is also challenged by the fact that unlike hedging say oil price risk or corn price risk, where a standard contract like Brent or CBT corn can provide a pretty good hedge for everyone, every pair of locations is a unique product that is not hedged effectively by an FTR based on another pair of locations. The market is therefore inherently fragmented, which is inimical to liquidity. This lack of liquidity is especially devastating during defaults.
So PJM (and other RTOs) faces a dilemma. As the Nasdaq event shows, even daily marking to market and variation margining can’t prevent defaults. Furthermore, moving to a no-credit system (like a CCP) isn’t foolproof, and is likely to be so expensive that it could seriously impair the FTR market.
We’ve seen two default examples in electricity this past summer. They won’t be the last, due the inherent nature of electricity.
Mr. Jackson has a just-so story that, well, just ain’t so. In his story, once upon a time US stock markets were faithful guardians of the public interest. Then, the SEC let them become for-profit firms, and it all went wrong:
Given power and a profit motive, even the most storied institutions will do what they must to maximize their wealth. And nowhere has this been more true than in our stock markets.
For over a century, exchanges were collectively owned not-for-profits, overseeing and organizing trading in America’s best-known companies. But about a decade ago, exchanges became private corporations, designed—perhaps even obligated—to maximize profits. Yet we at the SEC have far too often continued to treat the exchanges with the same kid gloves we applied to their not-for-profit ancestors. The result is that, even while one our fundamental mandates is to encourage competition, the SEC has stood on the sidelines while enormous market power has become concentrated in just a few players. That’s a key reason why among our 13 public stock exchanges, 12 are owned by just three corporations. And that’s how the stock exchanges that are a symbol of American capitalism have developed puzzling practices that look nothing like the competitive marketplaces investors deserve.
. . .
First, one might wonder how our stock markets got here. The answer is that stock exchanges have been better at extracting rents than regulators have been at stopping them. As you all know, in 1934, the Nation struck a bargain with our stock exchanges: the Commission was created to oversee the markets, and in turn the exchanges were given wide latitude in organizing their affairs. For generations, this system served investors well. But then the world changed, and the SEC allowed exchanges to become for-profit corporations with both regulatory and profit-seeking mandates.
At the time, the Commission didn’t sufficiently contemplate the effects that decision might have; we simply said that we saw no reason to think that exchanges couldn’t play the role of regulator and pursue profit at the same time. Maybe we were wrong. Whatever one thinks about the benefits or drawbacks of those events, we should all agree that for-profit companies can be counted on to do one thing: pursue profit. And in for-profit hands, SEC oversight designed for not-for-profit exchanges can be dangerous.
Where to begin?
Well, I guess I should begin by saying for probably the billionth time (here’s one of them) that stock markets were not non-profits out of some charitable motive, or to ensure that they acted in the public interest by self-regulating markets free of conflict of interest and mercenary motive. In fact, stock exchanges (and derivatives exchanges) adopted the not-for-profit form to protect the rents of their members. Furthermore, the exchanges self-regulated in ways that maximized the profits of their members: it is beyond a joke to say that exchanges are better at extracting rents today than during the halcyon non-profit years. Non-profit exchanges just extracted rents in different ways, and the rents did not flow through the exchange coffers. These different ways included naked collusion–which the SEC tolerated for years, kid gloves indeed!–as well as entry restrictions (the number of members remaining fixed since the 19th century) and various rules advantaging intermediaries (especially specialists, but also brokers).
As for conflicts of interest–they were rife in Commissioner Jackson’s good old days. The exchanges, as agents for their intermediary member-owners, had structural conflicts with the investing public.
Mr. Jackson argues that “modern exchanges tax ordinary investors.” The implicit claim is that old time exchanges didn’t. Ha! They just did it in different ways, and arguably levied far greater taxes then than now.
Why were the taxes arguably greater then? The answer relates to another fundamental error in Jackson’s just so story: “enormous market power has become concentrated in just a few players. That’s a key reason why among our 13 public stock exchanges, 12 are owned by just three corporations.” Er, prior to RegNMS, a little over a decade ago, and for the entire life of the SEC prior to that time, and prior to the formation of the SEC, the NYSE had a far more dominant position than any exchange does today. Due to network effects, it basically had a lock on order flow for its listings. Its market share was routinely above 85 percent, and that other 15 percent was basically cream skimming competition that the SEC only grudgingly accepted.
Again, the NYSE did not capture rents from this market power by charging higher prices and passing the revenues through to owners in the form of dividends. But through broker cartels, and after the SEC finally bestirred itself to end the broker cartels, through entry limits and rules that advantaged members, it permitted its members to earn rents by charging higher prices for their services.
Indeed, the great benefit of RegNMS is that it undermined the liquidity network effect that largely immunized the NYSE against competition, and unleashed competition for order flow unprecedented in the history of US stock markets–or stock markets anywhere, for that matter. Three (granting arguendo that 3 rather than 13 is the right number) is a helluva lot more competitive than one.
But Commissioner Jackson cannot see the glass is at least 90 percent full: he frets over the 10 percent (or less) that is empty. He laments “fragmentation.”
Yes. As I have written, the “fragmentation” (aka “competition”) that has occurred post-RegNMS has its costs–some of which are the result of problematic features in RegNMS. Others are inherent in any multi-market system. Fragmentation creates arbitrage opportunities that some participants capture through spending real resources: this is probably socially wasteful. Commissioner Jackson notes that these opportunities exist in part due to the lack of incentive of exchanges to invest in the public data feed: well, I’ve noted this public goods problem in the past (note the date–almost 5 years ago). Yes, some have information advantages due now mainly to speed: well, back in the day, people on the floor had information advantages–and speed advantages–due to their proximity to where price discovery was taking place. Take it as a law: there will always be a class of traders with information, access and speed advantages over the hoi polloi.
Some of these problems could be remedied by better regulation. But despite the deficiencies of RegNMS, there is no doubt that it made US equity markets far more competitive, and that this has redounded to the benefit of ordinary investors–and pretty much the entire buy side, including institutions. RegNMS dramatically reduced the “tax” that stock markets levied on investors, not increased it as Mr. Jackson apparently believes.
Commissioner Jackson questions whether the limited exposure to lawsuits that exchanges currently enjoy is justified. That is a legitimate question, but Mr. Jackson’s motivation for asking it is completely off-base. His fixation on for-profit again shines through: “Finally, we should take a hard look at whether it makes sense to allow for-profit exchanges to write the rules of the game for their customers and competitors while also enjoying immunity from civil liability.” Mr. Jackson: it is equally questionable whether it makes sense “to allow non-profit exchanges to write the rules of the game for their customers and competitors while also enjoying immunity from civil liability.”
Commissioner Jackson also questions pricing practices: “Finally, SEC and FINRA rules for best execution have clearly left open opportunities for conflicts of interest that hurt investors. The reason is that exchanges offer controversial payments—they call them rebates—to brokers based on the volume of customer orders that broker sends to that exchange.” This is a form of price competition. Yes, there are agency issues involved here, but if anything these rebates reduce the rents that exchanges earn that exercise Commissioner Jackson so greatly. Perhaps brokers don’t pass 100 percent of the rebates to their customers–but this is a distributive issue not an efficiency one, and competition between brokers mitigates this problem.
Perhaps in the category of “rebates” Commissioner Jackson is including maker-taker payments. But the interpretation of these payments–and the more prosaic order flow incentives Mr. Jackson describes–is greatly complicated by the fact that exchanges are multi-sided platforms. It is well-known that the pricing policies of multi-sided platformsoften involve cross-subsidies among customer groups (e.g., liquidity suppliers and liquidity demanders), and that these pricing strategies can be economically efficient.
US securities market structure could certainly be improved. But reasonable improvements must be grounded in a reasonable understanding of the economics of exchanges. Alas, one individual responsible for improving market structure is clearly operating from a seriously defective understanding. Commissioner Jackson’s bugbear–for-profit exchanges–have to a first approximation nothing to do with whatever ails US markets. He pines for an era that not only never existed, but which was in reality worse on almost every dimension that he criticizes modern markets for–competition, rent seeking, and conflicts of interest.
The SEC actually performed a public service–something not to be taken for granted for a public agency!–by breaking the liquidity network effect and opening stock markets to competition through the adoption of RegNMS. Tweak RegNMS to improve market performance, Commissioner Jackson, rather than advocating proposals based on just so stories that just ain’t–and weren’t–so.
The most important point: Nasdaq uses SPAN to calculate IM. SPAN was a major innovation back in the day, but it is VERY long in the tooth now (2018 is its 30th birthday!). Moreover, the most problematic part of SPAN is the ad hoc way it handles dependence risk:
Intra-commodity spreading parameters – rates and rules for evaluating risk among portfolios of closely related products, for example products with particular patterns of calendar spreads
Inter-commodity spreading parameters – rates and rules for evaluating risk offsets between related product
The CME SPAN methodology divides the instruments in each portfolio into groupings called combined commodities. Each combined commodity represents all instruments on the same ultimate underlying – for example, all futures and all options ultimately related to the S&P 500 index.
For each combined commodity in the portfolio, the CME SPAN methodology evaluates the risk factors described above, and then takes the sum of the scan risk, the intra-commodity spread charge, and the delivery risk, before subtracting the inter-commodity spread credit. The CME SPAN methodology next compares the resulting value with the short option minimum; whichever value is larger is called the CME SPAN methodology risk requirement. The resulting values across the portfolio are then converted to a common currency and summed to yield the total risk for the portfolio.
I would not be surprised if the handling of Nordic-German spread risk was woefully inadequate to capture the true risk exposure. Electricity spreads are strange beasts, and “rules for evaluating risk offsets” are unlikely to capture this strangeness correctly especially given the fact that electricity markets have idiosyncrasies that one-size-fits all rules are unlikely to capture. I also conjecture that Aas knew this, and loaded the boat with this spread trade because he knew that the risk was grossly underpriced.
There are reports that the Nasdaq margin breach at the time of default (based on mark-to-market prices) was not nearly as large as the €140 million hit to the default fund. In these accounts, the bulk of the hit was due to the fact that the price at which Aas’ portfolio was auctioned off included a substantial haircut to prevailing market prices.
Back in the day, I argued that one of the real advantages to central clearing was a more orderly handling of defaulted portfolios than the devil-take-the-hindmost process in OTC bilateral markets (cf., the outcome of the LTCM disaster almost exactly 20 years ago–with the Fed midwifed deal being completed on 23 September, 1998). (Ironically spread trades were the cause of LTCM’s demise too.)
But the devil is in the details of the auction, and in market conditions at the time of the default–which are almost certainly unsettled, hence the default. The CME was criticized for its auction of the defaulted Lehman positions: the bankruptcy trustee argued that the price CME obtained was too low, thereby harming the creditors. The sell-off of the Amaranth NG positions in September, 2006 (what is it about September?!?) to JP Morgan and Citadel (if memory serves) was also at a huge discount.
Nasdaq has been criticized for allowing only 4 firms to bid: narrow participation was also the criticism leveled at CME and NYMEX clearing in the Lehman and Amaranth episodes, respectively. Nasdaq argues that telling the world could have sparked panic.
But this episode, like Lehman and Amaranth before it, demonstrate the challenges to auctioning big positions. Only a small number of market participants are likely to have the capital, or the risk appetite, to take on a big defaulted position in its entirety. Thus, limited participation is almost inevitable, and even if Nasdaq had invited more bidders, there is room to doubt whether the fifth or sixth or seventh bidder would have been able to compete seriously with the four who actually participated. Those who have the capital and risk appetite to bid seriously for big positions will almost certainly demand a big discount to compensate for the risk of holding the position until they can work it off. Moreover, limited participation limits competition, which should exacerbate the underpricing problem.
Thus, even with a structured auction process, disposing of a big defaulted portfolio is almost inevitably something of a fire sale. This is a risk borne by the participants in the default fund. Although the exposure via the default fund is sometimes argued to be an incentive for the default fund participants to bid aggressively, this is unlikely because there are externalities: the aggressive bidder bears all the risks and costs, and provides benefits to the rest of the other members. Free riding is a big problem.
In theory, equitizing the risk might improve outcomes. By selling shares in the defaulted portfolio, no single or two bidders would have to absorb the entire position and risk could be spread more efficiently: this could reduce the risk discount in the price. But who would manage the portfolio? What are the mechanics of contributing to IM and VM? Would it be like a bad bank, existing as a zombie until the positions rolled off?
Another follow-up from my previous post relates to the issue of self-clearing. On Twitter and elsewhere, some have suggested that clearing through a 3d party would have been an additional check. Surely an FCM would be less likely to fall in love with a position than the trader who puts it on, but the effectiveness of the FCM as a check depends on its evaluation of risk, and it may be no smarter than the CCP that sets margins. Furthermore, there are examples of FCMs having the same trade in their house account as one of their big customers–perhaps because they think the client is really smart and they want to free ride off his genius. As a historical example, Griffin Trading had a big trade in the same instrument and direction as its biggest client. The trade went pear-shaped, the client defaulted, and Griffin did too.
I also need to look to see whether Nasdaq Commodities uses the US futures clearing model, which does not segregate positions. If it does, and if Aas had cleared through an FCM, it is possible that the FCM’s clients could have lost money as a result of his default. This model has fellow-customer risk: by clearing for himself, Aas did not create such a risk.
I also note that the desire to expand clearing post-Crisis has made it difficult and more costly for firms to find FCMs. This problem has been exacerbated by the Supplementary Leverage Ratio. Perhaps the cost of clearing through an FCM appeared excessive to Aas, relative to the alternative of self-clearing. Thus, if regulators blanch at the thought of self-clearing (not saying that they should), they should get serious about addressing the FCM cost issue, and regulations that inflate these costs but generate little offsetting benefit.
Again, this episode should spark (no pun intended!) a more thorough reconsideration of clearing generally. The inherent limitations of margin models, especially for more complex products or markets. The adverse selection problems that crude risk models can create. The challenges of auctioning defaulted portfolios, and the likelihood that the auctions will become fire sales. The FCM capacity issue.
The supersizing of clearing in the post-Crisis world has also supersized all of these concerns. The Aas blowup demonstrates all of them. Will CCPs and regulators take heed? Or will some future September bring us the mother of all blowups?
This was bound to happen. In a way, it was good that it happened in a relatively small market. But it provides a sobering demonstration of what I’ve said for years: clearing doesn’t eliminate losses, but affects the distribution of losses. Further, financial institutions that back CCPs–the members–are the ultimate backstops. Thus, clearing does not eliminate contagion or interconnections in the financial network: it just changes the topology of the network, and the channels by which losses can hit the balance sheets of big players.
Happening in the Nordic/European power markets, this is an interesting curiosity. If it happens in the interest rate or equity markets, it could be a disaster.
We actually know very little about what happened, beyond the broad details. We know Aas was long Nordic power and short German power, and that the spread widened due to wet weather in Norway (which depresses the price of hydro and reduces demand) and an increase in European prices due to increases in CO2 prices. But Nasdaq trades daily, weekly, monthly, quarterly, and annual power products: we don’t know which blew up Aas. Daily spreads are more volatile, and exhibit more extremes (kurtosis), but since margins are scaled to risk (at least theoretically–more on this below) what matters is the market move relative to the estimated risk. Reports indicate that the spread moved 17x the typical move, but we don’t know what measure of “typical” is used here. Standard deviation? Not a very good measure when there is a lot of kurtosis (or skewness).
I also haven’t seen how big Aas’ initial margins were. The total loss he suffered was bigger than the hit taken by the default fund, because under the loser-pays model, the initial margins would have been in the first loss position.
The big question in my mind relates to Nasdaq’s margin model. Power price distributions deviate substantially from the Gaussian, and estimating those distributions is challenging in part because they are also conditional on day of the year and hour of the day, and on fundamental supply-demand conditions: one model doesn’t fit every day, every hour, every season, or every weather enviornment. Moreover, a spread trade has correlation risk–dependence risk would be a better word, given that correlation is a linear measure of dependence and dependencies in power prices are not linear. How did Nasdaq model this dependence and how did that impact margins?
One possibility is that Nasdaq’s risk/margin model was good, but this was just one of those things. Margins are set on the basis of the tails, and tail events occur with some probability.
Given the nature of the tails in power prices (and spreads) reliance on a VaR-type model would be especially dangerous here. Setting margin based on something like expected shortfall would likely be superior here. Which model does Nasdaq use?
I can also see the possibility that Nasdaq’s margin model was faulty, and that Aas had figured this out. He then put on trades that he knew were undermargined because Nasdaq’s model was defective, which allowed him to take on more risk than Nasdaq intended.
In my early work on clearing I indicted that this adverse selection problem was a concern in clearing, and would lead CCPs–and those who believe that CCPs make the financial system safer–to underestimate risk and be falsely complacent. Indeed, I argued that one reason clearing could be a bad idea is that it was more vulnerable to adverse selection problems because the need to model the distribution of gains/losses on cleared positions requires detailed knowledge, especially for more exotic products. Traders who specialize in these products are likely to have MUCH better understanding about risks than a non-specialist CCP.
Aas cleared for himself, and this has caused some to get the vapors and conclude that Nasdaq was negligent in allowing him to do so. Self-clearing is just an FCM with a house account, but with no client business: in some respects that’s less risky than a traditional FCM with client business as well as its own trading book.
Nasdaq required Aas to have €70 million in capital to self-clear. Presumably Nasdaq will get some of that capital in an insolvency proceeding, and use it to repay default fund members–meaning that the €114 million loss is likely an overestimate of the ultimate cost borne by Nasdaq and the clearing members.
Further, that’s probably similar to the amount of capital that an FCM would have had to have to carry a client position as big as Aas’. That’s not inherently more risky (to the clearinghouse and its default fund) than if Aas had cleared through another firm (or firms). Again, the issue is whether Nasdaq is assessing risks accurately so as to allow it to set clearing member capital appropriately.
But the point is that Aas had to have skin in the game to self-clear, just as an FCM would have had to clear for him.
Holding Aas’ positions constant, whether he cleared himself or through an FCM really only affected the distribution of losses, but not the magnitude. If Aas had cleared through someone else, that someone else’s capital would have taken the hit, and the default fund would have been at risk only if that FCM had defaulted. But the total loss suffered by FCMs would have been exactly the same, just distributed more unevenly.
Indeed, the more even distribution that occurred due to mutualization which spread the default loss among multiple FCMs might actually be preferable to having one FCM bear the brunt.
The real issue here is incentives. My statement was that holding Aas’ positions constant, who he cleared through or whether he cleared at all affected only the distribution of losses. Perhaps under different structures Aas might not have been able to take on this much risk. But that’s an open question.
If he had cleared through another FCM, that FCM would have had an incentive to limit its positions because its capital was at risk. But Aas’ capital was at risk–he had skin in the game too, and this was necessary for him to self-clear. It’s by no means obvious that an FCM would have arrived at a different conclusion than Aas, and decided that his position represented a reasonable risk to its capital.
Here again a key issue is information asymmetry: would the FCM know more about the risk of Aas’ position, or less? Given Aas’ allegedly obsessive behavior, and his long-time success as a trader, I’m pretty sure that Aas knew more about the risk than any FCM would have, and that requiring him to clear through another firm would not have necessarily constrained his position. He would have also had an incentive to put his business at the dumbest FCM.
Another incentive issue is Nasdaq’s skin in the game–an issue that has exercised FCMs generally, not just on Nasdaq. The exchange’s/CCP’s relatively thin contribution to the default fund arguably reduces its incentive to get its margin model right. Evaluating whether Nasdaq’s relatively minor exposure to default risk led it to undermargin requires a more thorough analysis of its margin model, which is a very complex exercise which is impossible to do given what we know about the model.
But this all brings me back to themes I flogged to the collective shrug of many–indeed almost all–of the regulatory and legislative community back in the aftermath of the Crisis, when clearing was the silver bullet for future crises. Clearing is all about the allocation and pricing of counterparty credit risk. Evaluation of counterparty credit risk in a derivatives context requires a detailed understanding of the price risks of the cleared products, and dependencies between these price risks and the balance sheet risks of participants in cleared markets. Classic information problems–adverse selection and moral hazard (too little skin in the game)–make risk sharing costly, and can lead to the mispricing of risk.
The forensics about Aas blowing up real good, and the lessons learned from that experience, should focus on those issues. Alas, I see little recognition of that in the media coverage of the episode, and betting on form, I would wager that the same is true of regulators as well.
The Aas blow up should be a salutary lesson in how clearing really works, what it can do, and what it can’t. Cynic that I am, I’m guessing that it won’t be. And if I’m right, the next time could be far, far worse.
But Sperry doesn’t note two other facts that make this even more damning.
First after two of their operatives had been caught three years before, they would have gone back and tried to identify everyone they had interacted with. Everyone. They surely would have identified Page, not least because the statement of an FBI agent filed with the court in February, 2015 contained details that would have led them to identify Page as “Male-1.” Further, since the filing states that the FBI had interviewed “Male-1”, the Russians would have known that Page had cooperated with the FBI.
So this is a guy they are going to use as part of a clandestine scheme to bribe Donald Trump? Not in several thousand lives of the universe. They would have considered him a threat, not an opportunity.
The only way they would have used Page is to try to pass disinformation back to US intelligence.
Failing to detail Page’s full involvement with the prosecution and conviction of the Russian agents was therefore another crucial omission from the FISA warrant application. Given this information, Page’s plausibility as a Russian agent would have been zero.
Second, Sperry doesn’t remind us that after failing in its first try to get a FISA warrant on Page, a dossier report miraculously appears which contains the account of a meeting in which Sechin supposedly offered Trump, via Page, a stake in Rosneft. Presented with the new “information” of Page’s deep ties with the Russians, et voila!, the court issues the warrant.
This makes it highly likely–certain, in my view–that Steele was a short order cook serving up made-to-order material intended to advance the anti-Trump campaign. His–and the FBI’s/DOJ’s.
The FBI’s cynicism here is off the charts, and appalling. Carter Page helps them out in an investigation of Russian spies. But Peter Strzok and his fellow badged gangsters saw that Page was now useful in their attempt to sabotage Trump, so they viciously twisted his previous cooperation with them into evidence of connivance with Russian intelligence by leaving out the crucial details of his cooperation, the Russian views of him, and the likely Russian knowledge of him.
Moral of the story? Support your local sheriff, perhaps, but the FBI–you’d be a complete fool to do so, because they will F*** you sideways when it is in their interest to do so. Page is the poster boy for “no good deed goes unpunished.”
Carter Page should have a massive civil rights case against the US government, and the individuals who lied and conspired to deprive him of his 4th Amendment right against unlawful search and seizure–Strzok, McCabe, Comey, Yates, and others. And quite frankly, it should be a class action lawsuit, including in the class everyone who was surveilled, or whose communications were read, pursuant to the Page warrant.
Let’s hope that the karma for Page’s punishment for good deeds will far more draconian punishment of those who committed bad deed after bad deed when using Carter Page to achieve their sordid goals.
My first reaction is: where has Booker been all these years? This is hardly a new phenomenon. Exactly a century ago–starting in 1918–in response to concerns about, well, concentration in the meat-packing industry, the Federal Trade Commission published a massive 6 volume study of the industry The main theme was that the industry was controlled by five major firms. A representative subject heading in this work is “[m]ethods of the five packers in controlling the meat-packing industry.” “The five packers” is a recurring refrain.
The consolidation of the packing industry in the United States in the late-19th and early-20th centuries was a direct result of the communications revolution, notably the development of railroads and refrigeration technology that permitted the exploitation of economies of scale in packing. The industry was not just concentrated in the sense of having a relatively small number of firms–it was geographically concentrated as well, with Chicago assuming a dominant role in the 1870s and later, largely supplanting earlier packing centers like Cincinnati (which at one time was referred to as “Porkopolis”).
In other words, concentration in meat-packing has been the rule for well over a century, and reflects economies of scale.
Personal aside: as a PhD student at Chicago, I was a beneficiary of the legacy of the packing kings of Chicago: I was the Oscar Mayer Fellow, and the fellowship paid my tuition and stipend. My main regret: I never had a chance to drive the Weinermobile (which should have been a perk!). My main source of relief: I never had to sing an adaption of the Oscar Mayer Weiner Song: “Oh I wish I were an Oscar Mayer Fellow, that’s what I really want to be.”
Back to the subject at hand!
Booker also frets about vertical integration, and this is indeed a difference between the 2018 meat industry and the 1918 version: as the Union Stockyards in Chicago attested–by the smell, if nothing else–the big packers did not operate their own feedlots, but bought livestock raised in the country and shipped to Chicago for processing.
I am a skeptic about market power-based explanations of vertical integration, and there is no robust economic theory that demonstrates that vertical integration is anti-competitive. The models that show how vertical integration can be used to reduce competition tend to be highly stylized toys dependent on rather special assumptions, and hence are very fragile and don’t really shed much light on the phenomenon.
Transactions cost-based theories are much more plausible and empirically successful, and I would imagine that vertical integration in meat packing is driven by TCE considerations. I haven’t delved into the subject, but I would guess that vertical integration enhances quality control and monitoring, and reduces the asymmetric information problems that are present in spot transactions, where a grower has better information about the quality of the cattle, and the care, feeding, and growing conditions than a buyer.
I’d also note that some of the other industries Booker mentions–notably bean and corn processing–have not seen upstream integration at all.
This variation in integration across different types of commodities suggests that transactional differences result in different organizational responses. Grain and livestock are very different, and these likely give rise to different transactions costs for market vs. non-market transactions in the two sectors. It is difficult to see how the potential for monopsony power differs across these sectors.
Insofar as the major grain traders are concerned, again–this is hardly news. It was hardly news 40 years ago when Dan Morgan wrote Merchants of Grain.
Furthermore, Booker’s concerns seem rather quaint in light of the contraction of merchant margins, about which I’ve written a few posts. Ironically, as my most recent ABCD post noted, downstream vertical integration by farmers into storage and logistics is a major driver of this trend.
To the extent that consolidation is in play in grains (and also in softs, such as sugar), it is a reflection of the industry’s travails, rather than driven by a drive to monopolize the industry. Consolidation through merger is a time-tested method for squeezing out excess capacity in a static or declining industry.
Booker’s bill almost certainly has no chance of passage. But it does reflect a common mindset in DC. This is a mindset that is driven by simplistic understandings of the drivers of industrial structure, and is especially untainted by any familiarity with transactions cost economics and what it has to say about vertical integration.
I am still agog at the most flagrant public display of political onanism in living memory, by which I am of course referring to the McCain funeral.
Although ostensibly praising the deceased, the praise was really for the (unfortunately) still breathing–the political establishment. McCain was wonderful! McCain was one of us! Therefore, we are wonderful! Wonderful beyond words!
I was going to ask, rhetorically, whether these people could be THAT clueless? But the answer is obvious, which kind of saps the force of a rhetorical device.
This is nothing less than the political version of the Dunning-Krueger effect: an entire class of individuals with low ability, a history of poor performance, and a complete lack of perception and self-awareness, believing that they are God’s gift. And believing that the hoi polloi who voted for Trump are vicious ingrates for not recognizing how totally awesome the elites are.
Almost two years after the election, these people still fail to comprehend that the reason they have been rejected and scorned by tens of millions of ordinary Americans is their litany of failures post-1990. It is a record unblemished by success. A perfect record, in a perverse sense.
By failing even to question their own genius–and indeed, to loathe anybody who dares do so–they are only feeding the disdain in which they are held.
The cluelessness is crystalized in a tweet by a person laughably described as the Washington Post’s conservative voice–the truly repulsive Jennifer Rubin:
Just as 9/11/01 galvanized a generation of young people perhaps 9/1/18 (the date of McCain’s funeral) will be the inspiration for another generation of Americans to eschew tribalism and seek common ground in defense of overarching values. https://t.co/bFYb7UZqMU
It is disgusting enough to equate the Trump presidency to 9/11–and have no doubt that is what she is doing. The fact that she actually thinks that the funeral “eschew[ed] tribalism” is beyond belief. As I said in my post the other day–it was all about tribalism. It was the two clans of the political establishment tribe uniting to excoriate The Other under the pretense of having a funeral. Rubin’s assertion is an inversion of reality.
Several historical comparisons come to mind when thinking about the funeral bloviations.
The first is Talleyrand’s remark about the Bourbons, who learned nothing and forgot nothing.
The second is Pericles’ funeral oration. I watched a BBC show about the Spartans the other day in which the narrator summarized the oration as: “Everything about the Athenians is right. Everything about the Spartans is wrong.” Substitute the US political establishment for the Athenians, and Trump for the Spartans, and you have the McCain funeral orations to a “T”.
The third is that funeral was a perverse reversal of Mark Antony’s line in Julius Caesar. Instead of “I have come here to bury Caesar, not to praise him” the assembled bloviators in DC in effect said “we come here pretending to praise McCain, but actually to bury Trump.”
This got me thinking about some parallels between Rome in the 40s BC and DC today. Caesar was a member of the elite who appealed to the masses–both in the sense that he directed appeals to them, and that they found what he said appealing. He also insulted the elite at every turn, and implemented policies that attacked their interest and affronted their inflated sense of dignity. This frightened, incensed and enraged the Roman establishment, which was centered in the Senate. Caesar’s popularity, his disdain for the elite, and his refusal to kowtow before it, combined with the elite’s obsession with its power, privileges, and amour propre, brought the country into civil war.
No, history does not repeat, and late-Republican Rome is vastly different in many (most) ways from (hopefully not late-) Republican America (referring to the form of government, not the party). Yet the present spookily rhymes with the distant past, with Trump playing the role of Caesar, and the US Senate playing the role of, well, the Roman Senate.
Again, I’m not pushing the analogy too far. But there are enough points of comparison to make thoughtful people take pause. But, alas, the phrase “thoughtful people” is not one that describes the assembled “mourners” at McCain’s funeral, or their camp followers.
Robert Mueller brings to mind Dickens’ character Wilkins Micawber: “Something will turn up.” McCawber was vexed by his inability to strike it rich: Mueller by his inability strike the collusion goldmine he was tasked to find (perhaps unconstitutionally). While he is waiting for collusion to turn up, Mueller is hustling after penny ante process crimes.
The latest was a plea to the federal crime of failure to register as a foreign agent by lobbyist Sam Patten, whose heinous offense was to find someone who would buy tickets to Trump’s inauguration for a Ukrainian oligarch who tried to buy them directly–but was turned down by the Trump inauguration committee. In other words, if the guy tried to bribe Trump, he was rejected! That kinda contradicts the collusion narrative, don’t it?
Compared to this, jaywalking is mass murder.
And if justice were enforced blindly–I know, don’t laugh–would we have enough jails to hold all the malfeasors? For certainly with truly fair justice that is more than an exercise in scalp collecting to justify the continued existence of Mr. Mueller and his Merry Band, Mr. Patten should have plenty of company, starting with pretty much anyone involved with the dossier not to mention every lobbyist in DC.
It was sickly amusing to watch the hyperventilating media. The New York Times covered the story with five–five!–reporters. I know NYT reporters are pretty dim, but wouldn’t three have sufficed? Thursday night I saw a tweet by some media bigfoot (which of the idiots, I can’t remember) breathlessly advising us to read the news Friday, because Mueller would drop some bombshell in the morning. Instead, this dud landed with a thud.
The media is also barely able to contain itself over the claim by George Papadopolous (in his sentencing brief for his heinous process crime) that Trump nodded when George suggested a meeting with Putin. Nodded, I tells ya! Um, if Putin owned Trump–or had him “over a barrel”, in the words of Christopher Steele–why would it be necessary for George to suggest a meeting?
If it wasn’t so serious, this would be the most farcical farce in the history of farces. Alas, Micawber-Mueller’s waiting for something to turn up is morphing into waiting for Godot–a play with no point and seemingly no end. But it will go on, and on, and on, because it is in the interest of the political class for it to do so. So even if nothing turns up, its very existence has its political uses.